Termes les plus recherchés
[PDF](+69👁️) Télécharger Geometric Arbitrage and Spectral Theory pdf
Geometric Arbitrage Theory reformulates a generic asset model possibly allowing for arbitrage by packaging all assets and their forwards dynamics into a stochastic principal fibre bundle, with a connection whose parallel transport encodes discounting and portfolio rebalancing, and whose curvature measures, in this geometric language, the "instantaneous arbitrage capability" generated by the market itself. The cashflow bundle is the vector bundle associated to this stochastic principal fibre bundle for the natural choice of the vector space fibre. The cashflow bundle carries a stochastic covariant differentiation induced by the connection on the principal fibre bundle. The link between arbitrage theory and spectral theory of the connection Laplacian on the vector bundle is given by the zero eigenspace resulting in a parametrization of all risk neutral measures equivalent to the statistical one. This indicates that a market satisfies the no-free-lunch-with vanishing-risk condition if itTélécharger gratuit Geometric Arbitrage and Spectral Theory pdf
arXiv:1509.03264vl [q-fin.MF] 2 Sep 2015
Geometric Arbitrage and Spectral Theory
Simone Farinelli
Core Dynamics GmbH
Scheuchzerstrasse 43
CH-8006 Zurich
Email: simone@coredynamics. ch
September 11, 2015
Abstract
Geometric Arbitrage Theory reformulates a generic asset model pos¬
sibly allowing for arbitrage by packaging all assets and their forwards
dynamics into a stochastic principal fibre bundle, with a connection whose
parallel transport encodes discounting and portfolio rebalancing, and whose
curvature measures, in this geometric language, the "instantaneous arbi¬
trage capability” generated by the market itself. The cashflow bundle is
the vector bundle associated to this stochastic principal fibre bundle for
the natural choice of the vector space fibre. The cashflow bundle carries
a stochastic covariant differentiation induced by the connection on the
principal fibre bundle. The link between arbitrage theory and spectral
theory of the connection Laplacian on the vector bundle is given by the
zero eigenspace resulting in a parametrization of all risk neutral measures
equivalent to the statistical one. This indicates that a market satisfies
the no-free-lunch-with vanishing-risk condition if it is only if 0 is in the
spectrum.
Contents
1 Introduction
2 Geometric Arbitrage Theory Background
2.1 The Classical Market Model.
2.2 Geometric Reformulation of the Market Model: Primitives . . . .
2.3 Geometric Reformulation of the Market Model: Portfolios . . . .
2.4 Arbitrage Theory in a Differential Geometric Framework.
2.4.1 Market Model as Principal Fibre Bundle.
2.4.2 Numeraire as Global Section of the Bundle of Gauges . .
2.4.3 Cashflows as Sections of the Associated Vector Bundle . .
2.4.4 Stochastic Parallel Transport.
2.4.5 Nelson V Differentiable Market Model.
a
3
3
6
7
8
8
1C
10
12
1
2.4.6 Arbitrage as Curvature
3 Spectral Theory
3.1 The Connection Laplacian Associated to the Market Model . . .
3.2 Arbitrage and Utility.
4 Conclusion
A Derivatives of Stochastic Processes
12
M
15
18
[13
E3
1 Introduction
This paper further develops a conceptual structure - called Geometric Arbitrage
Theory - to link arbitrage modeling in generic markets with spectral theory.
GAT rephrases classical stochastic finance in stochastic differential geomet¬
ric terms in order to characterize arbitrage. The main idea of the GAT approach
consists of modeling markets made of basic financial instruments together with
their term structures as principal fibre bundles. Financial features of this market
- like no arbitrage and equilibrium - are then characterized in terms of standard
differential geometric constructions - like curvature - associated to a natural
connection in this fibre bundle. Principal fibre bundle theory has been heavily
exploited in theoretical physics as the language in which laws of nature can
be best formulated by providing an invariant framework to describe physical
systems and their dynamics. These ideas can be carried over to mathematical
finance and economics. A market is a financial-economic system that can be de¬
scribed by an appropriate principle fibre bundle. A principle like the invariance
of market laws under change of numeraire can be seen then as gauge invariance.
The vector bundle associated to the principal fibre bundle carries a covariant
differentiation induced by the connection. The connection Laplacian under the
Neumann boundary condition is a selfadjoint operator whose spectrum contains
0 if and only if the market model satisfies the no-free-lunch-with-vanishing-
risk condition. If 0 has simple multiplicity, then then market is complete, and
viceversa.
The fact that gauge theories are the natural language to describe economics
was first proposed by Malaney and Weinstein in the context of the economic in¬
dex problem (' |Ma96j . | We06| ). Ilinski (see [I100J and [IIP 1 1 ) and Young i I Yo99| )
proposed to view arbitrage as the curvature of a gauge connection, in analogy
to some physical theories. Independently, Cliff and Speed ( |SmSp98| ) further
developed Flesaker and Hughston seminal work ( |FlHu96] f and utilized tech¬
niques from differential geometry to reduce the complexity of asset models be¬
fore stochastic modeling.
This paper is structured as follows. Section 2 reviews classical stochastic
finance and Geometric Arbitrage Theory. Arbitrage is seen as curvature of a
principal fibre bundle representing the market which defines the quantity of
arbitrage associated to it. A guiding example is provided for a market whose
2
asset prices are Ito processes. Proof are omitted and can be found in IFal4j .
where Geometric Arbitrage Theory has been given a rigorous mathematical
foundation utilizing the formal background of stochastic differential geometry
as in Schwartz ( [Schw80l ). Elworthy ( [E1821 1. Emervf lEm89l ). Hackenbroch and
Thalmaier (' |HaTh94) h Stroock ( [StOOp and Hsu f |Hs02p . In Section 3 the
relationship between arbitrage and spectrum of the connection Laplacian, on
one hand, and between arbitrage and utility maximization on the other, are
investigated. Appendix A reviews Nelson’s stochastic derivatives. Section 4
concludes.
2 Geometric Arbitrage Theory Background
In this section we explain the main concepts of Geometric Arbitrage Theory
introduced in |Fal4l . to which we refer for proofs and examples.
2.1 The Classical Market Model
In this subsection we will summarize the classical set up, which will be rephrased
in section (12.41) in differential geometric terms. We basically follow IlhiKeOll
and the ultimate reference lDeSc081 .
We assume continuous time trading and that the set of trading dates is
[0, +oo[. This assumption is general enough to embed the cases of finite and
infinite discrete times as well as the one with a finite horizon in continuous time.
Note that while it is true that in the real world trading occurs at discrete times
only, these are not known a priori and can be virtually any points in the time
continuum. This motivates the technical effort of continuous time stochastic
finance.
The uncertainty is modelled by a filtered probability space (f2, A, P), where P
is the statistical (physical) probability measure, A = {At} te [o,+oo[ an increasing
family of sub-cr-algebras of Too and (fi, .Aoo,P) is a probability space. The
filtration A is assumed to satisfy the usual conditions, that is
• right continuity: At = P| s>t A s for all t G [0,+oo[.
• Ao contains all null sets of Aoo •
The market consists of finitely many assets indexed by j = 1,..., N, whose
nominal prices are given by the vector valued semimartingale S : [0, +oo[xf2 —»•
R n denoted by (S t )te[0,+oo[ adapted to the filtration A. The stochastic process
(St )te[o,+oo[ describes the price at time t of the j th asset in terms of unit of cash
at time t = 0. More precisely, we assume the existence of a Oth asset, the cash, a
strictly positive semimartingale, which evolves according to >Sf = exp (f dur°),
where the predictable semimartingale (r®) te [o i+00 [ represents the continuous in¬
terest rate provided by the cash account: one always knows in advance what
the interest rate on the own bank account is, but this can change from time to
time. The cash account is therefore considered the locally risk less asset in con¬
trast to the other assets, the risky ones. In the following we will mainly utilize
3
discounted prices, defined as Sj := S 3 /S representing the asset prices in
terms of current unit of cash.
We remark that there is no need to assume that asset prices are positive.
But, there must be at least one strictly positive asset, in our case the cash.
If we want to renormalize the prices by choosing another asset instead of the
cash as reference, i.e. by making it to our numeraire, then this asset must
have a strictly positive price process. More precisely, a generic numeraire is an
asset, whose nominal price is represented by a strictly positive stochastic process
(I?t)te[o,+oo[> anc ^ w hich is a portfolio of the original assets j = 0,1,2,... ,7V.
The discounted prices of the original assets are then represented in terms of the
numeraire by the semimartingales S° t := S 3 t /B t .
We assume that there are no transaction costs and that short sales are
allowed. Remark that the absence of transaction costs can be a serious limitation
for a realistic model. The filtration A is not necessarily generated by the price
process (£>t) te [o.+oo[ : other sources of information than prices are allowed. All
agents have access to the same information structure, that is to the filtration
A.
A strategy is a predictable stochastic process x : [0,+oo[xS2 —>• de¬
scribing the portfolio holdings. The stochastic process (a^)t£[o,-i-oo[ represents
the number of pieces of jth asset portfolio held by the portfolio as time goes by.
Remark that the Ito stochastic integral
/ x- dS = / x v ■ dS u . (1)
J o Jo
and the Stratonovich stochastic integral
f x o dS := f x ■ dS + — f d (x, S) = f x u ■ dS u + — f d(x, S) t
Jn Jo 2 Jr, Jn 2 J Q
( 2 )
are well defined for this choice of integrator ( S ) and integrand (a;), as long as the
strategy is admissible. We mean by this that a; is a predictable semimartingale
for which the Ito integral f Q x ■ dS is a.s. f-uniformly bounded from below.
Thereby, the bracket (-,-) denotes the quadratic covariation of two processes.
In a general context strategies do not need to be semimartingales, but if we
want the quadratic covariation in ([2]) and hence the Stratonovich integral to be
well defined, we must require this additional assumption. For details about
stochastic integration we refer to Appendix A in |Em89| . which summarizes
Chapter VII of the authoritative [DeMe80] . The portfolio value is the process
{^t}te[0,+oo[ defined by
V t := V t x := x t ■ S t . (3)
An admissible strategy x is said to be self-financing if and only if the portfolio
value at time t is given by
V t = V 0 + f x u ■ dS u .
Jo
(4)
4
This means that the portfolio gain is the Ito integral of the strategy with the
price process as integrator: the change of portfolio value is purely due to changes
of the assets’ values. The self-financing condition can be rewritten in differential
form as
dV t = x t ■ dS t . (5)
As pointed out in |BjHu05] , if we want to utilize the Stratonovich integral to
rephrase the self-financing condition, while maintaining its economical inter¬
pretation (which is necessary for the subsequent constructions of mathematical
finance), we write
V t = \o + [ x u o dS u f d(x, S) u (6)
J 0 ^ J 0
or, equivalently
dV t = xt o dS t -^d(x, S) t . (7)
An arbitrage strategy (or arbitrage for short) for the market model is
an admissible self-financing strategy x, for which one of the following condition
holds for some horizon T > 0:
• P[V 0 X < 0] = 1 and P[Vi f > 0] = 1,
• P[Vo < 0] = 1 and P[Vi f > 0] = 1 with P[V£ > 0] > 0.
In Chapter 9 of |DeSc08j the no arbitrage condition is given a topological charac¬
terization. In view of the fundamental Theorem of asset pricing, the no-arbitrage
condition is substituted by a stronger condition, the so called no-free-lunch-with-
vanishing-risk.
Definition 1. Let (£t)te[o,+oo[ be a semimartingale and (£t)te[ 0 ,+oo[ an d ad¬
missible strategy. We denote by (x • 5')+ 00 := lim t _>. +00 f* x u ■ dS u , if such limit
exists, and by Kq the subset of T°(fl, Aoo, P) containing all such (x ■ S )+ Qc .
Then, we define
• Co :=K 0 -L 0 + (n,Aoo,P).
• C := CoCL^iocP).
• C: the closure of C in L°° with respect to the norm topology.
The market model satisfies
• the 1st order no-arbitrage condition or no arbitrage (NA) if and
only if C H Aoo, P) = {0}, and
• the 2nd order no-arbitrage condition or no-free-lunch-with-vanishing-
risk (NFLVR) if and only if C Cl L°° (fl, Aoo,P) = {0}.
Delbaen and Schaclrermayer proved in 1994 (see [DeSc08l Chapter 9.4, in par¬
ticular the main Theorem 9.1.1)
5
Theorem 2 (Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing in Continuous
Time). Let (5't) t6 [o ! + 0 o[ and (St)te[0,+oo[ be bounded semimartingales. There
is an equivalent martingale measure P* for the discounted prices S if and only
if the market model satisfies the (NFLVR).
This is a generalization for continuous time of the Dalang-Morton-Willinger
Theorem proved in 1990 (see |UeSc08| . Chapter 6) for the discrete time case,
where the (NFLVR) is relaxed to the (NA) condition. The Dalang-Morton-
Willinger Theorem generalizes to arbitrary probability spaces the Harrison and
Pliska Theorem (see IDeSc08l . Chapter 2) which holds true in discrete time for
finite probability spaces.
An equivalent alternative to the martingale measure approach for asset pric¬
ing purposes is given by the pricing kernel (state price deflator) method.
Definition 3. Let (St)t^[ o,+oo[ be a semimartingale describing the price process
for the assets of our market model. The positive semimartingale (/3i)tg[o,+oo[
is called pricing kernel (or state price deflator) for S if and only if
(PtSt)t£[o,+oo[ is a P -martingale.
As shown in lHuKe04l (Chapter 7, definitions 7.18, 7.47 and Theorem 7.48),
the existence of a pricing kernel is equivalent to the existence of an equivalent
martingale measure:
Theorem 4. Let (St)te[ 0 ,+oo[ and (St)te[o,+oo[ be bounded semimartingales.
The process S admits an equivalent martingale measure P* if and only if there
is a pricing kernel fd for S (or for S ).
2.2 Geometric Reformulation of the Market Model: Prim¬
itives
We are going to introduce a more general representation of the market model
introduced in section 1241 which better suits to the arbitrage modeling task.
Definition 5. A gauge is an ordered pair of two A-adapted real valued semi¬
martingales ( D,P), where D = (D t )t >o : [0,+oo[xH —>- R is called deflator
and P = ( Pt,s)t,s ' T x — > R, which is called term structure , is considered
as a stochastic process with respect to the time t, termed valuation date and
T := {(f, s) £ [0,+oo[ 2 |s > t}. The parameter s > t is referred as matu¬
rity date. The following properties must be satisfied a.s. for all t,s such that
s>t> 0:
(i) Pt, s > 0,
(a) Pt,t = i.
Remark 6. Deflators and term structures can be considered outside the context
of fixed income. An arbitrary financial instrument is mapped to a gauge (D,P)
with the following economic interpretation:
6
• Deflator: D t is the value of the financial instrument at time t expressed
in terms of some numeraire. If we choose the cash account, the O-th asset
/\ • c<j
as numeraire, then we can set D-j. := S° t = ^ (j = 1,... N).
• Term structure: Pt tS is the value at time t (expressed in units of deflator
at time t) of a synthetic zero coupon bond with maturity s delivering one
unit of financial instrument at time s. It represents a term structure of
forward prices with respect to the chosen numeraire.
We point out that there is no unique choice for deflators and term structures
describing an asset model. For example, if a set of deflators qualifies, then
we can multiply every deflator by the same positive semimartingale to obtain
another suitable set of deflators. Of course term structures have to be modified
accordingly. The term ’’deflator” is clearly inspired by actuarial mathematics.
In the present context it refers to a nominal asset value up division by a strictly
positive semimartingale (which can be the state price deflator if this exists and
it is made to the numeraire). There is no need to assume that a deflator is
a positive process. However, if we want to make an asset to our numeraire,
then we have to make sure that the corresponding deflator is a strictly positive
stochastic process.
2.3 Geometric Reformulation of the Market Model: Port¬
folios
We want now to introduce transforms of deflators and term structures in order to
group gauges containing the same (or less) stochastic information. That for, we
will consider deterministic linear combinations of assets modelled by the same
gauge (e. g. zero bonds of the same credit quality with different maturities).
Definition 7. Letir : [0,+oo[ —> R be a deterministic cashflow intensity (possi¬
bly generalized) function. It induces a qauqe transform (D,P) M- ir(D,P ) :=
(A py := (D n , py by the formulae
D
7T
t
D t
dh 7 T h P ttt+h
/ 0 + °° dh 7 T h P t , s+h
/ 0 + °° dh TT h P t , t+ h
( 8 )
Proposition 8. Gauge transforms induced by cashflow vectors have the follow¬
ing property:
((a pyy = «A pyy = (a py*\ w
where * denotes
respectively:
the convolution product of two cashflow vectors or intensities
( 7 r* !/)*:= / dh7r h u t - h . ( 10 )
-'o
The convolution of two non-invertible gauge transform is non-invertible.
The convolution of a non-invertible with an invertible gauge transform is non-
invertible.
7
Definition 9. The term structure can be written as a functional of the instan¬
taneous forward rate f defined as
ft,a ■= log P t ,s, Pt,s = exp
OS
( 11 )
and
r t ■■= lim / t)S
s—»•£+
( 12 )
is termed short rate.
Remark 10. Since ( Pt, s )t,s is at-stochastic process (semimartingale) depending
on a parameter s > t, the s-derivative can be defined deterministically, and the
expressions above make sense pathwise in a both classical and generalized sense.
In a generalized sense we will always have a T>' derivative for any lo G fi; this
corresponds to a classic s-continuous derivative if Pt tS (iv) is a C 1 -function of s
for any fixed t > 0 and ui G fl.
Remark 11. The special choice of vanishing interest rate r = 0 or flat term
structure P = 1 for all assets corresponds to the classical model, where only
asset prices and their dynamics are relevant.
2.4 Arbitrage Theory in a Differential Geometric Frame¬
work
Now we are in the position to rephrase the asset model presented in subsection
m in terms of a natural geometric language. Given N base assets we want to
construct a portfolio theory and study arbitrage and thus we cannot a priori
assume the existence of a risk neutral measure or of a state price deflator. In
terms of differential geometry, we will adopt the mathematician’s and not the
physicist’s approach. The market model is seen as a principal fibre bundle
of the (deflator, term structure) pairs, discounting and foreign exchange as a
parallel transport, numeraire as global section of the gauge bundle, arbitrage
as curvature. The no-free-lunch-with-vanishing-risk condition is proved to be
equivalent to a zero curvature condition.
2.4.1 Market Model as Principal Fibre Bundle
Let us consider -in continuous time- a market with N assets and a numeraire.
A general portfolio at time t is described by the vector of nominals x G X,
for an open set X C IR^. Following Definition [5j the asset model induces for
j = 1, • • •, N the gauge
= {(D J t ) te[0t+oo[ ,(Pl s ) s > t )
(13)
where D J denotes the deflator and P J the term structure. This can be written
8
where J- 7 is the instantaneous forward rate process for the j-th asset and the
corresponding short rate is given by r J t \= lim„_>o+ flu- For a portfolio with
nominals x G X C IR^ we define
N
IK ■■=
3 =1
N
flu ■■= E
X 3 D l
=1 2^j=
j =i
r-jD J t
flu
TDX
-t + o •
:= exp
The short rate writes
(15)
“ lim fl u =
u^f 0+
N
x j D l
E iv
i=i
N
-i X
jD'l
7
r t ■
(16)
The image space of all possible strategies reads
M := {(a:,t) G X x [0,+oo[}.
(17)
In subsection 12.31 cashflow intensities and the corresponding gauge transforms
were introduced. They have the structure of an Abelian semigroup
G := £'([0, +oo[, IR) = {F € X>'([0, +oo[) | supp(F) C [0, +oo[ is compact},
. (18)
where the semigroup operation on distributions with compact support is the
convolution (see IHondl . Chapter IV), which extends the convolution of regular
functions as defined by formula m-
Definition 12. The Market Fibre Bundle is defined as the fibre bundle of
gauges
B := {{D” t x ,P” t , x )\(x,t) G M,n € G*}. (19)
The cashflow intensities defining invertible transforms constitute an Abelian
group
G* := {7r G G\ it exists v G G such that n * v = [0]} C £'([(), +oo[, R). (20)
From Proposition [5] we obtain
Theorem 13. The market fibre bundle B has the structure of a G*-principal
fibre bundle given by the action
B x G* —> B
((D,P),n)^(D,Py = {D\P”) (21)
The group G* acts freely and differentiably on B to the right.
2.4.2 Numeraire as Global Section of the Bundle of Gauges
If we want to make an arbitrary portfolio of the given assets specified by the
nominal vector £ Num to our numeraire, we have to renormalize all deflators by
an appropriate gauge transform 7T 1S!um ’ x so that:
9
• The portfolio value is constantly over time normalized to one:
^Num _Num
D x t = 1.
( 22 )
• All other assets’ and portfolios’ are expressed in terms of the numeraire:
D
„Num
= FXf
Df
Df
(23)
It is easily seen that the appropriate choice for the gauge transform 7 r Num making
the portfolio x Num to the numeraire is given by the global section of the bundle
of gauges defined by
Num.x
:= FX°f^ x
(24)
Of course such a gauge transform is well defined if and only if the numeraire
deflator is a positive semimartingale.
2.4.3 Cashflows as Sections of the Associated Vector Bundle
By choosing the fiber V := R[ 0 ’+°°[ and the representation p : G — > GL(V)
induced by the gauge transform definition, and therefore satisfying the homo¬
morphism relation p(gi * < 72 ) = p(si)p(S 2 ), we obtain the associated vector
bundle V. Its sections represents cashflow streams - expressed in terms of the
deflators - generated by portfolios of the base assets. If v = (vf )t x ,t)eM is the
deterministic cashflow stream, then its value at time t is equal to
• the deterministic quantity vf , if the value is measured in terms of the
deflator Df,
• the stochastic quantity vf Df. if the value is measured in terms of the
numeraire (e.g. the cash account for the choice D 3 t := Sf for all j =
In the general theory of principal fibre bundles, gauge transforms are bundle
automorphisms preserving the group action and equal to the identity on the
base space. Gauge transforms of B are naturally isomorphic to the sections
of the bundle B (See Theorem 3.2.2 in [B181] l. Since G* is Abelian, right
multiplications are gauge transforms. Hence, there is a bijective correspondence
between gauge transforms and cashflow intensities admitting an inverse. This
justifies the terminology introduced in Definition [7]
2.4.4 Stochastic Parallel Transport
Let us consider the projection of B onto M
p : B = M x G* —> M
(x,t,g) i-> (x,f)
(25)
10
and its tangential map
T( x ,t,g)P : T(x,t,g)B^ *
• T{x,t)M
(26)
SR N xlRxlR[ 0 .+ ao [
SIR" xR.
The vertical directions are
V( x ,t,g)B • ker f —
R[0’ + o°[,
(27)
and the horizontal ones are
(28)
A connection on B is a projection TB —> VB. More precisely, the vertical
projection must have the form
x,t,g) ■ T{x,t,g)B * V(x,t,g)B
(6x,6t,6g) (0, 0,Sg + T(x,t,g).(6x,6t)),
and the horizontal one must read
^-(x,t,g) ■ T( Xt t,g)& > 'H( Xt t g )B
(Sx,St,Sg) (5x,St, —T(x,t, g).(6x,6t)),
(29)
(30)
such that
rr + n^iB. (3i)
Stochastic parallel transport on a principal fibre bundle along a semimartingale
is a well defined construction (cf. |HaTh94l . Chapter 7.4 and lHst)2l Chap¬
ter 2.3 for the frame bundle case) in terms of Stratonovic integral. Existence
and uniqueness can be proved analogously to the deterministic case by formally
substituting the deterministic time derivative ^ with the stochastic one T> cor¬
responding to the Stratonovich integral.
Following Ilinski’s idea ( |I101j j. we motivate the choice of a particular con¬
nection by the fact that it allows to encode foreign exchange and discounting as
parallel transport.
Theorem 14. With the choice of connection
T{x,t,g).(5x,5t) := g
(32)
the parallel transport in B has the following financial interpretations:
• Parallel transport along the nominal directions (x-lines) corresponds to a
multiplication by an exchange rate.
• Parallel transport along the time direction (t-line) corresponds to a division
by a stochastic discount factor.
Recall that time derivatives needed to define the parallel transport along
the time lines have to be understood in Stratonovich’s sense. We see that the
bundle is trivial, because it has a global trivialization, but the connection is not
trivial.
11
2.4.5 Nelson V Differentiable Market Model
We continue to reformulate the classic asset model introduced in subsection 12 .II
in terms of stochastic differential geometry.
Definition 15. A Nelson V differentiable market model for N assets is
described by N gauges which are Nelson T> differentiable with respect to the
time variable. More exactly, for all t £ [0,+oo[ and s > t there is an open
time interval I 9 t such that for the deflators D t := [D \,..., D ^]' and the
term structures Pt iS := [Pf s ,...,P t N s y, the latter seen as processes in t and
parameter s, there exist a V t-derivative. The short rates are defined by rt :=
lim s _j.(- ^log P t s-
A strategy is a curve 7 : I —> X in the portfolio space parameterized by the
time. This means that the allocation at time t is given by the vector of nominals
Xt := 7 {t). We denote by 7 the lift of 7 to M, that is 7 (f) := ( 7 (f), t). A
strategy is said to be closed if it represented by a closed curve. A T>-admissible
strategy is predictable and T>-differentiable.
In general the allocation can depend on the state of the nature i.e. xt = Xt(u>)
for w £ ft.
Proposition 16. A D-admissible strategy is self-financing if and only if
V(x t ■ D t ) = x t ■ VD t - i (x, D) t or Vx t ■ D t = ~{x, D ) t , (33)
almost surely.
For the reminder of this paper unless otherwise stated we will deal only with
V differentiable market models, T> differentiable strategies, and, when necessary,
with V differentiable state price deflators. All fto processes are V differentiable,
so that the class of considered admissible strategies is very large.
2.4.6 Arbitrage as Curvature
The Lie algebra of G is
g = r[°’ +0 °[
and therefore commutative. The fz-valued connection 1-form writes as
( rjSx \
—jy£ ~ r t St J 9,
or as a linear combination of basis differential forms as
X(x, t,g) = D t dx i ~ r t dt ) g '
3 =1
The g-valued curvature 2-form is defined as
R := d\+ [x,x],
(34)
(35)
(36)
(37)
12
meaning by this, that for all ( x,t,g ) G B and for all £, 77 £ T( x>t )M
R(x,t,g){£,r)) := dx(x, t, g){f, rf) + [x(x,t, g){^),x{x,t, g)(rj)\. (38)
Remark that, being the Lie algebra commutative, the Lie bracket [•, •] vanishes.
After some calculations we obtain
N
R {x,t,g) = (rf +V\og(D x t ) - r J t -Vlog (£>£)) dxj A dt, (39)
t jSi
summarized as
Proposition 17 (Curvature Formula). Let R be the curvature. Then, the
following quality holds:
R{x, t, g) = gdt A d x [D log (Df) + rf]. (40)
We can prove following results which characterizes arbitrage as curvature.
Theorem 18 (No Arbitrage). The following assertions are equivalent:
(i) The market model satisfies the no-free-lunch-with-vanishing-risk condition.
(ii) There exists a positive semimartingale ft = 0 such that deflators and
short rates satisfy for all portfolio nominals and all times the condition
rf =-Vlog(p t Df). (41)
(Hi) There exists a positive semimartingale ft = (ftt)t >0 such that deflators
and term structures satisfy for all portfolio nominals and all times the
condition
TJX
r t,
S
ttWsDf]
Pt.Df
(42)
This motivates the following definition.
Definition 19. The market model satisfies the Oth order no-arbitrage con¬
dition or zero curvature (ZC) if and only if the curvature vanishes a.s.
Therefore, we have following implications relying the three different definitions
of no-abitrage:
Corollary 20.
2nd order no-arbitrage => 1st order no-arbitrage => Oth order no-arbitrage
(NFLVR)
(NA)
(ZC)
(43)
13
As an example to demonstrate how the most important geometric concepts of
section [2] can be applied we consider an asset model whose dynamics is given
by a multidimensional multidimensional Ito-process. Let us consider a market
consisting of N + 1 assets labeled by j = 0,1,...,TV, where the 0-th asset
is the cash account utilized as a numeraire. Therefore, as explained in the
introductory subsection 12. 11 it suffices to model the price dynamics of the other
assets j = 1,,N expressed in terms of the 0-th asset. As vector valued
semimartingales for the discounted price process S : [0, +oo[xft —> R v and the
short rate r : [0,+oo[xf2 —> R^, we chose the multidimensional Ito-processes
given by
dS t = S t (a t dt + <r t dW t ),
dr t = atdt + btdWt,
(44)
where
• (Wt^g^+ool is a standard P-Brownian motion in R A , for some K G N,
and,
• ( cr t)te[o,+oo[, (at)te[o,+oo[ are R , NxK -, and respectively, R A - valued locally
bounded predictable stochastic processes,
• (6 t )te[0,+oo[) ( a *)te[o,+oo[ are R NxL and respectively, R jV - valued locally
bounded predictable stochastic processes.
Proposition 21. Let the dynamics of a market model be specified by (44\ )-
Then, the market model satisfies the 0th no-arbitrage condition if and only if
a t~\ (°1 w )t+ r t e Range(a t ). (45)
If the volatility term is deterministic, i.e ert(u;) = at, this condition becomes
a t +r t G Range(a t ). (46)
Remark 22. In the case of the classical model, where there are no term struc¬
tures (i.e. r = 0), the condition (4f>\ reads as at € Range(at).
Proposition 23. For the market model whose dynamics is specified by the
no-free-lunch-with-vanishing risk condition (no 2nd order arbitrage) is equiva¬
lent with the zero curvature condition (no 0th order arbitrage) if
E
< +oo,
(47)
for all x £ R w . This is the Novikov condition for the instantaneous Sharpe
Ratio —.
14
3 Spectral Theory
3.1 The Connection Laplacian Associated to the Market
Model
Ilinki’s connection x on the market principal fibre bundle B induces a covariant
differentiation V on the associated vector bundle V. More exactly, we have
Proposition 24. Let X = Jff^oXj g|- be a vector field over M and f = (f t )t
a section of the cashflow bundle V. Then
j=o J
where
Kq (x) = —r*
Di (49)
Kj(x) = ^ (1 <j<N).
Proof. The construction of a covariant differentiation on the associated vector
bundle starting from a connection A on a principle fibre bundle is a generic
procedure in differential geometry. The Ilinski connection % is a Lie algebra
Q = [R[ 0 -+°°[ valued 1-form on M, and, we can decompose the connection as
X(x,g) = gK(x), were K(pc) := o Kj(x)dxj. The tangential map T e p : Q —>
£([r[o,+o°[) 0 £ re p resen tation p : G —> GL(R[ 0 ’ +o °[) maps elements of the
Lie algebra on endomorpliisms for the bundle V. Given a local cashflow section
ft = / 0 + °° ds fsSs-t, in V |u an d a local vector field X in TM\jj the connection
V has a local representation
r+oo
V.Y /= / ds(dfs(e).v s + f s ui{X).v s ), (50)
J 0
where v s := d s -t and ui is an element of T*U\u (^) C(V\u) i.e. an endomorphism
valued 1—form defined as
u(x) := T e .x{x,e) =
as
p (exp(eA(x, e)e).
£ = 0
Since the derivative of the exponential map is the identity and
p{ 7r) = 7T * • e GL(V X ) T e p.t = t * • g C(V X ),
it follows that
oj( x) = A(x, e) * ■ = K{x)8 * •,
(51)
(52)
(53)
15
and, therefore
V.Y / =
r+oo
/ ds [df 8 (X)v 8 + f s K.X5 * t; s ] =
do
r +oo
= / ds[d/ s (A) + / s A7X]<; s =
J o
= df t (X) + f t K.X =
i=o J
( 54 )
□
We now continue by introducing the connection Laplacian on an appropriate
Hilbert space
Definition 25. The space of the sections of the cashflow bundle can be made
into a scalar product space by introducing, for stochastic sections f = f(t, x, ui) =
(/*(<,£, w)) se[0 , + oo[ and g = g(t,x,u) = (g s (t,x,uj)) se[ o, +00 [
C f,g ) := / dP f d N x
Jn J x
r+oo
(f,g)(uj,t,x) := / dsf 8 (u>, t, x)g s (uj, t, x).
Jo
The Hilbert space of integrable sections reads
H ■= {/ = f(t,X,Uj) = {f S (t, X, w))s€[0,+oo[| (/,/) < +°o} • (56)
A standard result functional analysis is, if we see the u> dependence as a
parameter
Proposition 26. The connection Laplacian A := V*V with domain of defini¬
tion given by the Neumann boundary condition
dom( A) := {/ € H\ f(u, ; ■) € H 2 (M , V) V v /(w, •, -)\ dM = 0 Vw € fl} (57)
is a selfadjoint operator on TL. Its spectrum lies in [0,+oo[.
The spectrum of the connection Laplacian under the Neumann boundary
condition contains information about arbitrage possibilities in the market. More
exactly,
Theorem 27. The market model satisfies the (NFLVR) condition if and only if
0 € spec(A). The harmonic sections parametrize the Radon-Nykodim derivative
for the change of measure.
r+oo
dt (/, g) (u>,t,x), where
(55)
16
Proof. The spectrum of the Laplacian under Neumann boundary conditions
contains 0 if and only if there exists a section / such that
V/ = 0.
By Proposition [M] this is equivalent with
djf
dxj
+ Kjft = 0 ,
for all j = 0,1,..., N. This means
2 ?log(/ t )-r*=0,
and, for j = 1,..., N,
dlogjft) _ Dj
dx> Df
Therefore, there exists a positive process /3 = (/3t)te[o,+oo[ such that
ft =
1
(58)
(59)
(60)
(61)
(62)
and
V\og(p t Df) + r? = 0 (63)
For fixed u g f! the Laplace operator has an elliptic symbol and by Weyl’s
theorem any harmonic f = ft = f(u,t,x) is a smooth function of ( t,x ). In
particular any path of / is cadlag with bounded variation, and, hence, (ft)t is
a semimartingale. By equation (1621) . being ( D t )t a semimartingale, it followas
that {Pt)t is a semimartingale as well. By Theorem [TS] this is equivalent to the
(NFLVR) condition. □
Remark 28. Any harmonic f = ft{x) defines a risk neutral measure by means
of the Radom-Nykodim derivative
dP* Pt D x t fo(x)
dP fa D x 0 f t (x ) ’
(which does not depend on x).
From formula (1641) we derive
Corollary 29. The market model satisfies is complete if and only if 0 € spec( A)
is an eigenvalue with simple multiplicity.
17
3.2 Arbitrage and Utility
Let us now consider a utility function, that is a real C-function of a real variable,
which is strictly monotone increasing (i.e. u! > 0) and concave (i.e. u" < 0).
Typically, a market participant would like to maximize the expected utility of its
wealth at some time horizon. Let us assume that he (or she) holds a portfolio
of synthetic zero bonds delivering at maturity base assets and that the time
horizon is infinitesimally near, that is that the utility of the instantaneous total
return has to be maximized. The portfolio values read as:
• At time t - h: Df_ h Pf_ ht+h .
• At time t: DfPf t+h .
• At time t + h: Df +h .
Proposition 30. The synthetic bond portfolio instantaneous return can be com¬
puted as :
Rett := lim Et-h
h— »0+
r^x _ t^x tdx
^t+h Lj t-h jr t-h,t+h
9 h D x P x
* lllJ t-h r t-h,tA-h
= Plog (Df)+r?
Proof. We can develop the instantaneous return as
(65)
lim E t _/,
h— >-0+
T^iX _ nx TJX
^t-\-h J -'t—h J ~t—h,t-\-h
9 h D x P x
£llLJt-h r t-h,t+h
= lim E t _ h
h- 5-0+
= lim —— VD
h-> o+ Df
D x _ d x
u t+h u t-h
2 h D x P x
* ni -'t-h jr t-h i t+h
l -Pi
t—h,t-\-h
2 hPf
t—h,t+h
exp ds ff_ h s ) - 1
2 h
= V log D : l
( 66 )
□
Remark 31. This portfolio of synthetic zero bonds in the theory corresponds
to a portfolio of futures in practice. If the short rate vanishes, then the future
corresponds to the original asset.
Definition 32 (Expected Utility of Synthetic Bond Portfolio Return).
Let t > s be fixed times. The expected utility maximization problem at time s
for the horizon T writes
sup E s
I — f-^h} h>8
exp / dt (2?log(Df*)+rf‘) D x /P t
S,T
(67)
where the supremum is taken over all V-differentiable self-financing strategies
*£ — {•Eu}‘w> 0 *
Now we can formulate the main result of this subsection.
18
Theorem 33. The market curvature vanishes if and only if all market agents
maximize their expected utility for all times and horizons.
This result can be seen as the natural generalization of the corresponding result
in discrete time, as Theorem 3.5 in |FoSc04| . see also }Ro94 . Compare with
Bellini’s, Frittelli’s and Schachermayer’s results for infinite dimensional opti¬
mization problems in continuous time, see Theorem 22 in |BeFr02| and Theorem
2.2 in [SchaOlj . Nothing is said about the fulfilment of the no-free-lunch-with-
vanishing-risk condition: only the weaker Oth order no-arbitrage condition is
equivalent to the maximization of the expected utility at all times for all hori¬
zons.
Proof. The optimization problem (1671) into a standard problem of stochastic op¬
timal theory in continuous time which can be solved by means of a fundamental
solution of the Hamilton-Jacobi-Bellman partial differential equation.
However, there is a direct method, using Lagrange multipliers. First, re¬
mark that problem (1321) is a convex/concave optimization problem with convex
domain and concave utility function and has therefore a unique solution corre¬
sponding to a global maximum. The Lagrange principal function corresponding
to the this maximum problem writes
$(x,A):= E s
exp (J\t (2? log (D?)+r?)\ Df°Pf; r
- \(Dx h ■ D h + - (x, D) h ).
( 68 )
The Lagrange principal equations associated to this maximization problem read
5 $
dx
u ' (exp (V dt (VlogiDf) + rf*)] D :r s °Pff\
exp ^ dt (27log(£>f‘) + rf )J D^Pfy
j T dt^-{V\og{D?)+r?)
(69)
= 0 ,
dQ 1
— = -Vx h ■ D h - - ( x , D) h =0 (Ae [s, T]),
where A denotes the Lagrange multiplier corresponding to the self financing
condition, the second equation. The first equation shows no contribution from
the constraint because -§^Vx h = V-§^x h = 0 and {x h ,D h ) = = 0.
Since the equation system must hold for all s and T such that T > s, it follows
— (2?l O g(D*‘)+rf*) = 0.
(70)
Therefore, it exist a positive process j3 = (/3t)t>o, (which is a priori not a semi
martingale), such that
V\og{p t D x t ') + rV =0, (71)
19
and thus by Proposition 1171 since for t = s this must hold true for any initial
condition x s £ R^, the curvature must vanish. Therefore: if the maximization
problem has a solution, then the equation system has a solution, implying by
Theorem [lH] the Oth oder no-arbitrage condition for the market. Conversely, if
the Oth oder no-arbitrage condition is satisfied, the equation system must have
a solution by Theorem [T8l
□
If the asset dynamics follows an Ito process, Proposition l23l and Theorem l33l
lead to
Corollary 34. For the market model whose dynamics is specified by an ltd’s
process 0 satisfying Novikov’s condition 0. the (NFLVR) condition holds
true if and only if all market agents maximize their expected utility for all times
and horizons.
4 Conclusion
By introducing an appropriate stochastic differential geometric formalism the
classical theory of stochastic finance can be embedded into a conceptual frame¬
work called Geometric Arbitrage Theory, where the market is modelled with a
principal fibre bundle with a connection and arbitrage corresponds to its curva¬
ture. The associated vector bundle, termed cashflow bundle, carries a covariant
differentiation induced by the connection. The presence of the eigenvalue 0 in
the spectrum of the connection Laplacian characterizes the fulfillment of no-
free-lunch-with-vanishing-risk condition for the market model.
A Derivatives of Stochastic Processes
In stochastic differential geometry one would like to lift the constructions of
stochastic analysis from open subsets of R jV to N dimensional differentiable
manifolds. To that aim, chart invariant definitions are needed and hence a
stochastic calculus satisfying the usual chain rule and not Ito’s Lemma is re¬
quired, (cf. |HaTh94l . Chapter 7, and the remark in Chapter 4 at the beginning
of page 200). That is why we will be mainly concerned in this paper by stochas¬
tic integrals and derivatives meant in Stratonovich’s sense and not in ltd’s.
Definition 35. Let I be a real interval and Q = (Qt)tei be a vector valued
stochastic process on the probability space (f i,A,P). The process Q determines
three families of a-subalgebras of the a-algebra A:
(i) ’’Past” Vt : generated by the preimages of Borel sets in RA by all mappings
Q s : Q, R N for 0 < s < t.
(ii) ’’Future” dFt, generated by the preimages of Borel sets in R w by all map¬
pings Q s : LI —> R w for 0 < t < s.
20
(in) ’’Present” Aft, generated by the preimages of Borel sets in R w by the
mapping Q s : LI —> R w .
Let Q = (Qt)t£i be continuous. Assumi
Lire la suite
- 254.75 KB
- 15
Vous recherchez le terme ""

69

64

45